“Development in South Asia

for the International Encyclopedia of Social and Behavioral Sciences

David Ludden

University of Pennsylvania

2/19/01

 

ABSTRACT

 

As a collection of institutional activities to employ public and private assets for public benefit, development articulates the ideas and the powers of its effective participants.  The history of modern development in South Asia began in the 1840s, when government began investing in infrastructure to increase capital accumulation in the British Empire.  After 1880, nationalists organized public pressure to make development serve the nation.  In 1947, national governments attained supremacy in development for about thirty years, when state planning prevailed.  After 1980, national autonomy and state capacities for leadership in development declined as its effective participants multiplied and global investors expanded their role.  Today, development has no one guiding vision or dominant logic.  Disparate institutions pursue disparate goals including free market globalization, economic growth, ending poverty, and empowering the poor majority of citizens who have never had their own strong voice in development.

ARTICLE

Development can be understood as an activity, a condition, an event, or a process.  In social science, development is most often studied as a complex of institutional activities that employ both public and private assets for public benefit. It takes many forms according to ideas and environments that guide its conduct and condition its results.  Policies, institutions, outcomes, and analysis together constitute development as a process that is distinct from the related processes of economic growth and social progress, because development explicitly includes the activities of state authorities who establish public priorities and implement policy, includes official relationships among people inside and outside the state, includes public assessments of policy, and includes political efforts to change policy. 

Objects and trajectories of development are defined and measured variously.  There is thus a vast literature on economic, political, social, cultural, industrial, agricultural, technological, moral, and human development.  Even economic development can be assessed by different yardsticks: aggregate increases in national wealth and productivity are common measures; but national autonomy, food security, and social stability are often important priorities; and a particular state regime's stability, revenue, military might, and cultural legitimacy often preoccupy policy makers.  Primary, secondary, explicit, and implicit priorities typically jostle in policy making and various measures of success are typically used by various participants in development debates.

Economic development is the subject of this essay.  Though "the economy" as studied by economics consists primarily of markets, "an economy" is a more complex environment that includes natural endowments, social power relations, and political history.  Economic development embraces all the institutional and material conditions that constitute specific economies.  Because development requires the self-conscious use of power by particular groups in specific contexts, development regimes represent formations of organized power that define the history of development. 

In South Asia, pre-modern regimes developed regional economies before 1800.  A modern development regime emerged under British rule after 1800.  National regimes took over development after 1945.  Since 1970, the leadership capacities of national regimes have declined as international trends have favored global investors and struggles to represent the poor and previously marginal peoples have favored local movements and non-governmental organizations.

In 1929, an erudite British agricultural officer, William Moreland, concluded from his research that the "idea of agricultural development was already present in the fourteenth century.”  His conclusion can now be extended much further back in time, because now we know that ancient and medieval rulers in South Asia invested to increase productivity, most prominently by organizing irrigation.  By the fourteenth century, royal finance and protection were also expanding markets and manufacturing by building transportation infrastructure.  By the eighteenth century, state activities that developed agriculture, commerce, and manufacturing flourished around capital cities in Bengal, Gujarat, Punjab, the Indo-Gangetic plains, and the peninsular river basins. 

Pre-modern regimes increased state revenue and enriched bankers, farmers, and manufacturers.  But they worked in what Moreland called a “political and social environment …unfavourable to [modern goals of development],” because, he said, military and political struggles undermined investments in farming, manufacturing, and banking, as pillage and plunder fed destructive armies and rapacious taxation fattened unproductive ruling elites.[1]

The British imperial development regime was built upon a pre-modern legacy but introduced new ideas, institutions, and priorities.  In 1776, Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations became Britain's first modern treatise on economic development.  Smith attacked Crown support for monopolies like the East India Company and promoted the expansion of commerce as the nation's top development priority.  British conquest in South Asia proceeded from the mid-eighteenth to the late nineteenth century as Britain became the world's foremost industrial nation.  Industrialization helped to sustain the imperial enterprise and vice versa.  Modern imperialism defined the first institutional framework for modern economic development in the United Kingdom, British India, Ceylon, and other colonial territories. 

Until the 1840s, Indian tax revenues were assigned primarily to meet the cost of conquest, administration, and imperial finance.  Policy priorities shifted over decades onto laissez faire lines to open India for Britain's commercial interests.  In 1813, Parliament renewed the Company charter but ended its trading monopoly and allowed private merchants freer access to British territories overseas.  In 1833, Parliament made the Company an administrative institution and made English the official language of state law, administration, and education.  British India became a territory for imperial development inside a world empire; and in 1833,  the abolition of slavery triggered petitions from Caribbean planters that spurred the Indian government to send shiploads of indentured workers from Calcutta to keep English sugar plantations running in the West Indies. 

British industrial interests were prominent in imperial development policy.  As early as 1793, public debates ensued on how to best manage of "Asiatic possessions" in the national interest.[2]  Increasingly prohibitive tariffs against Indian cloth protected Lancashire, and after 1815, Lancashire sent cloth virtually free of tariffs to India.  As Smith predicted, British consumers benefited from commercial imperialism.  English merchants sold Bengal opium in China to buy tea and porcelain for English households; sugar from Caribbean plantations sweetened English tea.  Monetary policy kept relative prices of the Indian rupee and English pound favourable for English investors, importers, exporters, and consumers.  In 1818, James Mill's History of British India composed a British national history, justification, and ideology for British governance in India; and English businessmen were soon cutting Indians out of commercial partnerships to garner national benefits from the imperial trades.

The real value of taxes in India rose rapidly as prices dropped from 1823 to 1854.  During this long price depression, it became more cost effective to invest Indian taxes in India.  At the same time, outlets for British industrial capital were being sought in London and supply systems for industrial raw materials were being developed.  In the 1840s, London launched plans for building infrastructure in India to cheapen English supplies of commodities and raw materials, to expand military operations, to increase revenue, and to extend British capital investments in plantations, railways, cities, roads, ports, shipping, irrigation, and other ventures. 

In the 1840s, an irrigation engineer, Arthur Cotton, argued forcefully that Indian crop production and could be advanced by state irrigation investments that would pay for themselves with higher taxes on more productive land. [3]  At the same time, a commission of Parliament met to consider ways to improve supplies of raw cotton to Lancashire mills.  Bombay Presidency attracted special attention, along with Egypt.[4]  Measures were sought to expand cotton exports from these regions to counter-balance England's dependence on cotton supplies from the American South.  When the US Civil War broke out, Egypt and India filled a void in cotton supplies created by the Union blockade of Confederate ports.

A transition to a modern development regime consumed the decades 1840-1880.  In 1853, Governor General Dalhousie announced a plan to build an Indian railway with state contracts that guaranteed English companies a minimum five percent return; and to secure that return, government kept control of railway construction and management.  In 1871, the Government of India obtained authority to raise loans for productive purposes, and large irrigation projects began, following earlier success raising revenues from smaller projects.  Development projects were all government endeavours that employed many native contractors and their benefits also filtered down to native owners of land receiving new irrigation and producing commodity crops. 

By 1880, regions of specialized production for world markets had been developed in South Asia.  Ceylon was a plantation economy.  Coffee plantations expanded from fifty to eighty thousand acres between 1847 and 1857, and peasants devoted another forty-eight thousand acres to coffee for export.  Coffee acreage expanded another 35,000 acres in the 1860s.  In the 1880s, leaf disease killed coffee cultivation, which was rapidly replaced by tea, rubber, cocoanut, and cinchona plantations.  Ceylon and India replaced China as the major suppliers of English tea.  British plantation investors drove out peasant producers and controlled export markets.  Labour supplies posed the major constraint for tea planters, and the solution was found in the institution of (eventually permanent) labour migration from southern Tamil districts in British India.  British plantations in Malay colonies also depended on migrating Tamil workers.

British Burma and East Africa also developed in circuits of capital accumulation anchored in India.  In Burma, Tamil Chettiyar bankers became prime financiers for agricultural expansion in the Irrawaddy River delta, which generated huge exports of rice for world markets, including India, where urbanization increased demand for imported rice.  In East and South Africa, merchants from Gujarat and emigrant workers from Bombay, Calcutta, and Madras provided both labour and capital for railway construction and formed urban nuclei for the colonial economy.  Between 1896 and 1928, seventy-five percent of emigrants from Indian ports went to Ceylon and Malaya; ten percent, to Africa; nine percent, to the Caribbean; and the remaining six percent, to Fiji and Mauritius, which also became island plantation economies. 

The Deccan plateau in India's peninsula became cotton country.  In 1876, cotton duties were abolished in England to further cheapen supplies from India, and a year later, the biggest famine ever recorded struck Deccan cotton-growing districts.  Under laissez faire economic policy and imperial bureaucracy, little was done to alleviate famine suffering, but famine sharpened government attention to investments in protective irrigation. Famine commissions and policies were implemented. 

By 1914, most goods arriving at South Asia ports were destined for export: cotton, wheat, rice, coal, coke, jute, gunny bags, hides and skins, tea, ores, and wool.  Most cotton came to Bombay from Maharashtra.  All tea came to Calcutta and Colombo from British-owned plantations in Assam, Darjeeling, and hills around Kandy.  Most export rice came to Rangoon.  Wheat came primarily from fields under state irrigation in Punjab (60%) and the western United Provinces (Uttar Pradesh) (26%).  Oilseeds came to Bombay from Hyderabad territory (Andhra Pradesh), the Central Provinces (Madhya Pradesh), and Bombay Presidency (Maharashtra).  Coal, coke, and ores came from mines around Jharkhand into Calcutta and Bombay, where they stoked local industry as well as exports.  Eastern Bengal (Bangladesh) produced almost all the world's jute, which went to Scotland and then to Calcutta, where jute cloth output surpassed Dundee by 1908.

Between 1880 and 1914, industrial development in India took off during decades of low prices in Europe and America when rising prices in South Asia encouraged investments in India by firms producing for Indian markets and for diversified world markets.  Commodity prices in India rose with export commodity production until 1929.   Imported industrial machinery was domesticated in new Indian factory towns.  It 1853, the first Indian cotton mill appeared in Bombay, and the Factory Act (1881) imposed rules on Indian factories to reduce their comparative advantage in virtue of low labour costs and cheap access to raw materials in India.  In 1887,  J.N.Tata's Empress Mill arose at Nagpur, in the heart of cotton country, in 1887.  The Tatas became India's industrial dynasty. Tata Iron and Steel Works at Jamshedpur consumed increasing supplies of ore and coal, which by the 1920s rivalled exports from Calcutta.  In 1914, India was the world's fourth largest industrial cotton textile producer: cotton mills numbered 271 and employed 260,000 people, 42% in Bombay city, 26% elsewhere in Bombay Presidency (mostly Nagpur), and 32% elsewhere in British India, at major railway junctures. Coal, iron, steel, jute and other industries were developed at the same time, producing specialized regional concentrations of heavy industrial production around Bombay, Ahmedabad, Nagpur, Kanpur, Calcutta, Jamshedpur, and Madras. [5]  Jute mills around Calcutta multiplied from 1 to 64, between 1854 and 1914; the number of looms and scale of employment increased twice as fast.   In 1913, manufactured goods comprised twenty percent of Indian exports that were valued at ten percent of national income, figures never since surpassed.

World War One stimulated policies to enhance India's industrialization to make India less dependent on imports; and the Great Depression, 1929-1933, again boosted incentives for industrial growth by reducing prices for farm output compared to manufactures.  As a result, industrial output in British India grew steadily from 1913 to 1938 and was 58% higher at the end of the Depression than at the start of World War One; compared to slower and more uneven rates of growth in the UK and Germany.[6]   By contrast, plantations languished from the early 1900s to the 1940s, the major exception being rubber, which benefited from war booms.  Native States and non-British firms participated in the industrial trend.  In 1902, Mysore government installed an electric generator built by General Electric with techniques and equipment pioneered at Niagara Falls.  Bangalore was the first South Asian city lighted with electricity.  In 1921, a third of India's industrial production was driven by electricity and Mysore had a higher proportion of electrified industry (33%) than British Indian provinces of Madras (13%) or Bengal (22%). 

By 1920, South Asia had institutionalized national economies dominated by agriculture but also including large public sectors and major industries.  Indian investors and nationalist politicians were by this time vocal advocates for increasing state development efforts.  By 1920, British India was also a land of opportunity for global investors.  In 1914, the US Consul at Bombay, Henry Baker, had called it "one of the few large countries of the world where there is an 'open door' for the trade of all countries."[7]  England was still India's dominant trading partner, but it was losing ground.  In 1914, the UK sent 63% of British India's imports and received 25% of its exports; and by 1926, these figures stood at 51% and 21%, respectively.  By 1926, total trade with the UK averaged 32% for the five major ports (Calcutta, Bombay, Madras, Karachi, and Rangoon).  Bombay and Rangoon did 43% of their overseas business with Asia and the Middle East.  Calcutta did a quarter of its business with America.[8] 

South Asia's early globalization also appears in migration data.  In 1911, the British in British India numbered only 62% of all resident Europeans (54% in Native States and Agencies).  Four times more immigrants came into India from Asia than from Europe and seven of ten came overland from Nepal (54%) and Afghanistan (16%).  In 1911, Nepalis entering British India (280,248) exceeded the resident British population by fifty percent; Asian immigrants were three times as many.  By 1921, emigration far exceeded immigration.  Between 1896 and 1928, 83% of 1,206,000 emigrants left British India from Madras (which accounted for only 10% of total overseas trade), and they mostly went to work in Ceylon (54%) and Malaya (39%).  Bombay emigrants went mostly to East and South Africa; Calcutta emigrants, to Fiji and the West Indies.[9] 

In 1920, Britain still controlled the highest echelons of South Asia's political economy, but process of capital accumulation inside South Asia had escaped British control.  Before the war, London's political position in South Asia seemed secure.  After the war, London declined visibly in relation to other metropolitan powers and also to cosmopolitan powers in South Asia that were mobilizing for national control of development.  A national development regime emerged inside the British Empire.  In 1920, the Indian government obtained financial autonomy from Britain. 

Indian nationalists focused sharply on economic issues. The Indian National Congress first met in Bombay, in 1885, and then met every year in late December in a different city of British India.  Following the Deccan famines, in1879, Dadabhai Naoroji published his influential The Poverty of India to document the negative economic impact of imperial policies on India, and he presided at Congress meetings in 1886, 1893, and 1906, where delegates from all the provinces discussed government policy and argued for lower taxes and increased state development expenditure.  In 1905, the Congress launched a Swadeshi Movement to induce Indian consumers to buy Indian made cloth rather than British imports. 

The Great Depression dramatized the social cost of India's open imperial economy: it sparked peasant and worker's movements demanding economic security and spurred nationalist efforts to make government more responsible for public well-being in India.  By this time, government had long experience as an economic manager and investor in infrastructure.  Government owned and managed most mineral and forest resources.  Government agricultural departments, colleges, and experiment stations supported scientists and engineers who worked on state-funded development projects.  The vast state sector of the imperial economy was managed, however, within a laissez faire policy framework that favoured foreign investors. 

In 1930, the new Congress president, Jawaharlal Nehru, announced new ambitions for national development.  He took nationalist economic thought in a new direction when he said, "the great poverty and misery of the Indian People are due, not only to foreign exploitation in India but also to the economic structure of society, which the alien rulers support so that their exploitation may continue," and he went on to proclaim that "In order therefore to remove this poverty and misery and to ameliorate the condition of the masses, it is essential to make revolutionary changes in the present economic and social structure of society and to remove the gross inequalities."[10]

Bitter experience of state failure, social disruption, and mass death during the Great Depression, the Great Bengal Famine (1943-4), and the Partition of British India (1947) laid the groundwork for national planning that stressed national autonomy, security, and economic integration under strong state leadership.  In 1951, Prime Minister Nehru chaired India's Planning Commission, and in the 1950s, all South Asian countries wrote national plans stressing self-sufficiency and addressing problems of national economic growth, poverty, and inequality. 

Three decades from the start of India's first Five Year Plan in 1952 to the end of its Sixth Plan in 1985 were the heyday of nationally planned development in South Asia.  This was also the most creative period for development theory, a practical strain of economic thought devoted to increasing the productivity and well-being in nations emerging from European imperial control. 

National planning required the institutional enclosure of national economies.  Around the world, national economies were more self-contained in the 1950s and 1960s than they had been in the heyday of European imperialism.  Foreign direct investment declined globally from roughly ten percent of world output in 1913 to less than five percent in the 1960s, when the rate of increase in world merchandise exports was well below the 1.7 percent that pertained from 1870 to 1914. 

South Asia's national plans focused on national markets.  National planners formulated priorities for allocating state resources acquired both internally and externally.  External funds came in grants and loans from countries involved in the Cold War as well as from the Bretton Woods institutions sponsored by the richest capitalist countries.  National plan allocations for  agriculture and industry were intended to enhance private investment.  Planning instituted a new public-and-private apparatus for monitoring national economies.  Planning agencies organized regional and local initiatives like cooperative societies and community development programs.  National governments set up public food procurement and distribution systems to establish a ceiling on food costs for the poor.  National health and education expanded.  State ownership expanded to basic industries, public utilities, banks, and insurance. 

Economic progress became a central feature of national discourse.  Public intellectuals and organizations representing farmer, worker, business, and other interests became intensely involved in planning debates as the national public was mobilized politically under the universal adult franchise.  In order to address national needs, however, deficit spending increased demands for external funding; and national economic growth depended on private capital rather than on poor voters.  Finance and politics pushed national planning in opposing directions.  Popular participation favoured citizen groups while financial pressures favoured major investors. 

Plans initially focused on industrial import substitution and on producing basic goods in public sector enterprises.  Even so, eight-percent of India's industrial production remained in the private sector, where public sector output lowered input prices.  Protective controls on imports, exports, and operations inside national markets were stricter than ever before and spawned a regulatory bureaucracy as well as black and grey markets.  Plan allocations were in practice mixed in with political patronage.  By the late 1960s, foreign exchange shortages began to put private and public sector companies into direct competition for funding.  Nehru died in 1964.  Drought and famine struck India in 1965-1967 and the food distribution system relied on US foreign aid.  As a result, planners thrust new energy into the Green Revolution, which combined irrigation, pesticides, and high-yielding hybrid wheat and rice seeds.  Plans concentrated on extending the Green Revolution by investing in sites of intensive cultivation where well endowed landowners controlled local labour, finance, and political institutions.  Critics called this strategy "betting on the rich."  Defenders saw the Green Revolution as the foundation of national food security.

During the 1970s, state planning began to lose its grip on development.  Policy makers in Sri Lanka, Bangladesh, and Nepal were first to shift priorities away from national autonomy as they sought to meet demands from the urban middle class and rural landowners by using massive external assistance for large development projects, epitomized by the Mahaveli scheme in Sri Lanka, then the largest irrigation project in the world.  New external debt came with new conditions.  From 1973, rising oil prices brought recession along with inflation to rich countries in Europe and North America, as it drove up the cost of South Asia's industrial growth, middle class consumption, and the Green Revolution.  The effects were most drastic in smaller South Asian countries, which began borrowing on a much higher scale and soon came under structural adjustment policies introduced by the World Bank and International Monetary Fund, where development theory had shifted to focus on government policy reform in borrowing countries.  Among economists, critics of national state control of development became more influential.

In 1981, India also began to rely more heavily on foreign debt.  By 1990, internal pressure from middle class consumers and major industrial concerns combined with conditions imposed by external lenders to force the liberalization of economic policies in favour of freer market operations.  State policy shifted away from regulated planning toward institutional reforms, which have preoccupied government since 1991 and opened India's economy substantially. 

The eighties and nineties witnessed a profound shift in relationships among participants in development.  Dismantling central government controls, opening governments to public scrutiny and popular participation, and making the state more accountable and transparent for private citizens became the order of the day.   In India, private capital and state governments gained more independence from a central government that is today composed of shifting coalitions of regionally-based parties, rather than being dominated by a single national party.  State governments gained powers to make contracts with foreign countries and businesses.  State Chief Ministers now compete to attract investors.  In Nepal, electoral democracy was established in 1991, opening development to wide public debate at the same time as foreign investments grew.  In Pakistan, a national government threatened by struggles for regional autonomy also had to absorb disruptions from two decades of war in Afghanistan, leading to more stringent authoritarianism.  Since 1981, Sri Lanka has been wracked by war with Tamil regional separatists; and like Bangladesh, it depends on foreign investors while it struggles to resist reforms that undermine national sovereignty. 

The problem of governance became increasingly central in debates about development.  Since 1980, active institutional participants in development have multiplied in all the countries as global investors have increased their power inside national economies.  Together, these two trends have weakened the capacities of national governments to maintain strong leadership.  At the same time, government reform and privatization of public enterprise has become a policy priority in international funding agencies.  Effective governance in development has scattered and fragmented, while the responsibility of the national state for macro-economic management, property and human rights protection, and political stability has become more demanding.  

Development today has no one guiding vision or dominant logic and several contradictory trends are prominent.   National economies are more global as are the cultural communications that shape national politics.  In the 1990s, television media owned by multinational corporations flooded public information systems.  The growth of exports from South Asian countries measured 13.5% annually in the 1990s, almost four times the rate of the 1970s.  Foreign direct investment (FDI) grew, though it remains a small proportion of India's GDP at 0.1 percent before 1991 and 0.5 percent in 1992-6.  In 1990-1996, FDI increased (in millions of US dollars) from under 100 to over 5,000 in India, from under 250 to over 650 in Pakistan, from under 60 to over 600 in Bangladesh, and from under 60 to over 2,400 in Sri Lanka.  In the first six months of 1996 alone, Korean companies made nine technical and twenty-five financial agreements in India.

Forging alliances between national and international business now preoccupies national policy makers and linkages between FDI and national investors are increasing the pool of investment capital inside national economies.  A repeat of the nineteenth century trend that created specialized economic regions is underway.  In Nepal, tourism and hydro-electricity attract foreign and domestic partnerships.  In Bangladesh, the garment industry has been the fastest growing employer, relying on imports for all material inputs and exporting all its output.  Sri Lanka is a free-trade zone.  The South Indian cities of Bangalore and Hyderabad are growth nodes for high technology and business collaboration.  The Sylhet region of Bangladesh specializes in labour exports to Britain. 

Globalization has not fostered much cooperation among South Asian countries; rather, national governments and business compete in world markets.  More market activity crossing national borders escapes regulation and monitoring.  External labour migration has reached staggering proportions but is impossible to assess empirically.  The largest overseas flow is to the Persian Gulf, where Bangladesh alone sent 1,600,000 workers in 1995.  Available data indicate that only a fraction of remittances are recorded and that most flow through informal channels to finance domestic consumption, investment and foreign trade in the migrants' home country.  Illegal trades also flourish in drugs and arms; organized crime has gone beyond its old interest in black market radios and videos to trafficking in women and child sex-workers.

More citizen groups have become vocal critics of state leadership, priorities, and administrative practice in development.  Popular movements against the Narmada Dam in India and against the Arun Three hydro-electric project in Nepal represent many mobilizations to make development more respectful of the environment and responsible to people marginalized and displaced by state development projects. 

Countless grassroots movements now seek to wrest control of development from national states.  These include regional and local democratic movements fighting for the interests of farmers, workers, industrialists, women, and the poor; they also include the Maoist insurgency that has spread like wildfire in Nepal, Tamil separatists in Sri Lanka, and militant struggles for autonomy among tribal peoples in several mountain regions. 

Non-governmental organizations (NGOs) have become prominent development institutions. NGOs number in the hundreds of thousands.  Most are small and locally financed but some have grown huge by combining local initiatives with government funding, international finance, and business activity.  In 1976, the Grameen Bank was established by Muhammad Yunnus in Bangladesh to make small loans to poor women and today it counts its clients in the millions and values its loans in billions of dollars.  Despite its size, however, Grameen still reaches a tiny proportion of the rural poor in Bangladesh. 

Contemporary development includes contradictory tendencies that do not form one dominant trend.  Globalization, regionalism, and localization are progressing at the same time.  The conventional use of national statistics to study development has become inadequate as economic conditions have become more disparately local, regional, national and global in their form and content.  Overall economic growth accelerated in the 1990s, but there were also a series of good monsoons, poverty did not decline significantly, and inequalities as well as instability and conflict over development increased. 

Who is leading development, who is benefiting, and where today's trends are moving remain debatable.  Some analysts have said that development itself is dead.  It is more accurate to say that development entered a new phase in the last decades of the twentieth century when increasingly numerous, vocal, and contentious participants organized effectively to pursue disparate, perhaps contradictory goals, including free market globalization, economic growth, ending poverty, and empowering the poor majority of citizens in South Asia who have never had their own effective institutional voice.

 

 

BIBLIOGRAPHY

 

Agarwal, Anil & Sunita Narain. Towards Green Villages; A Strategy for Environmentally-Sound and Participatory Rural Development. New Delhi: Centre for Science and Environment, 1989.

Bagchi, Amiya Kumar, "Development Planning" In The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, editors Murray Milgate and Peter Newman John Eatwell. London: 1989.

Barber, William. British Economic Thought and India 1600-1858:  A Study in the History of Development Economics . Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1975.

Bardhan, Pranab. The Political Economy of Development in India. Bombay: Delhi Oxford University Press, 1984.

Chandra, Bipan. The Rise and Growth of Economic Nationalism in India: Economic Policies of Indian National Leadership. New Delhi: People's Publishing House, 1966.

Chaudhuri, Pramit. India's Economy: Poverty and Development. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1979.

Dreze, Jean and Amartya Sen editors. Indian Development: Selected Regional Perspectives. Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1998.

Frankel, Francine R. India's Political Economy, 1947-1977: The Gradual Revolution. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1978.

Habib, Irfan. An Atlas of Mughal Empire:  Political and Economic Maps With Notes, Bibliography and Index. Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1982.

Hossain, Moazzem, Iyanutul Islam and Reza Kibria. South Asian Economic Development: Transformations, Opportunities and Challenges. London: Routledge, 1999.

Johnson, B. L. C. Development in South Asia. Harmondsworth, England: Penguin, 1983.

Kabeer, Naila. Reversed Realities: Gender Hierarchies in Development Thought. London: Verso, 1994.

Kothari, Rajni. The Political Economy of Development. Bombay: Orient Longman, 1971.

Kumar, Dharma. Editor. The Cambridge Economic History of India, Vol. 2, circa 1757-1970.  Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1970.

Leys, Colin. The Rise and Fall of Development Theory. Nairobi and Bloomington: EAEP and Indiana University Press, 1996.

Mahbub ul Haq Human Development Centre. Human Development in South Asia 1999. Dhaka: The University Press Limited, 1999.

Myrdal, Gunnar. Asian Drama: An Inquiry into the Poverty of Nations. NY: Random House, 1968.

The Post-Development Reader, Editors Majid with Victoria Bawtree Rahnema. Dhaka: University Press Limited, 1997.

Raychaudhuri, Tapan and Irfan Habib. Editors. The Cambridge Economic History of India, Vol.1 circa c.1200-c.1750. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1970.

Tomlinson, B. R. The New Cambridge History of India: The Economy of Modern India, 1860-1970. New Delhi: Foundation Books.



[1]  William Moreland, The Agrarian System of Moslem India, Cambridge, 1929 (reprint Delhi, 1968), pp.205-6.

[2] Historical View of Plans for the Government of British India and Regulation of Trade to the East Indies and Outlines of a Plan of Foreign Government, of Commercial Economy, and of Domestic Administration for the Asiatic Interests of Great Britain. London, J.Sewell and J. Debrett, 1793.

[3]  Arthur Thomas Cotton, Lectures on irrigation works in India; delivered at the School of Military Engineering, Chatham, autumn session, 1874, by Arthur Cotton. Collected and Published by Uddaraju Raman,  Vijayawada, 1968.

[4] British Parliamentary Papers. Reports from Committees, 1847-1848. Volume 9. "Report from the Select Committee on the Cultivation of Cotton in India."

[5] Department of Statistics, Government of India, Inland Trade (Rail and River-borne) of India, 1919-1920, Calcutta, 1921.

[6] Morris D. Morris, "The Growth of Large-Scale Industry to 1947," in The Cambridge Economic History of India, volume II, c.1757-c1970, Dharma Kumar, editor, Cambridge, 1983, pp. 569, 576, 609.

[7] US Department of Commerce, Special Consular Reports, No.72, British India, with notes on Ceylon, Afghanistan, and Tibet, Washington, Government Printing Office, 1915, p.9.

[8] Annual Statement of the Sea-Borne Trade of British India with the British Empire and Foreign Countries for the fiscal year ending 31st March, 1926, Calcutta, Government of India, 1926, Table 10

[9]  A Historical Atlas of South Asia, Joseph E. Schwartzberg, editor, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1978, p. 115.

[10] A. Moin Zaidi, editor, A Tryst With Destiny: A study of economic policy resolutions of the Indian National Congress passed during the last 100 years, New Delhi, 1985, p.54.